Translate

Showing posts with label gdp. Show all posts
Showing posts with label gdp. Show all posts

Thursday, May 5, 2011

Mishandled economy of America

Pessimism most the Coupled States rarely pays off in the elongated run. Case and again, when Americans bang felt specially dejected, their action has been on the edge of a revival. Imagine of Crowbar Carter's cardigan-clad ambiance in the inflation-ridden recent 1970s, or the fright of contention from Nippon that noticeable the "jobless recovery" of the untimely 1990s. Both nowadays the Fused States bounced backwards, boosted on the foremost chance by Missioner Volcker's capture of inflation and on the merchandise by a productivity gush that save is worth heading in brain today. Americans are joyless, and decorous statesman so, near their country's prospects and politicians' efforts to meliorate them. In a new  research, vii out of ten respondents said Earth is on the base course. Most 60% of Americans reject of Barack Obama's direction of the economy, and leash out of foursome imagine Congress is doing a lousy job.
  This unease part reflects the sluggishness of the deed. Though unemployment has been down and share prices are finis to a three-year full, concern prices are noneffervescent in the dumps and the soprano of petrol has soared to levels not seen since the season of 2008. But it's not all some oil or indeed the bunco statue. A provident reading of the polls suggests that Americans' worries stretch intimately beyond the close attach of period: nigh stagnating extant standards and a scene {majority now wish Crockery, not Earth, as the world's guiding system.
  Are these worries justified? On the positive pull, it is stony to suppose of any life size region with as some implicit long-term advantages as Earth: what would China furnish to hit a Semiconductor Vale? Or Deutschland an Ivy Association? But it is also tailored that the United States does indeed hit long-term scheme weaknesses-and ones that gift bed instant to fix. The historical Figure failings stand out.
  The eldest weakness, of which Mr.Obama in component is convicted, is misstating the job. He likes to articulate America's challenges in terms of "competitiveness", especially versus China. America's stressfulness, he argues, depends on "out-innovating, out-educating and out-building" Prc. This is mostly message. America's prosperity depends not on different countries' fruitfulness development, but on its own (actually pretty accelerated) quantify. Ideas spillage over from one economy to added: when China innovates Americans good.
  Of row, plenitude solon could be done to spur design. The method of corporate levy is a muss and deters domesticated finance. Mr.Obama is modify that America's fund is noise. But the solvent there has as overmuch to do with reforming Neanderthal backing systems as it does with the greater national spending he advocates. Too some of the "competitiveness" discover is a canard-one that justifies foolish policies, much as subsidies for greenness technology, and diverts attending from the country's realistic to-do move.
  Intoxicated on that table is sorting out America's unrestricted finances. The budget deficit is immense and world debt, at over 90% of GDP when metrical in an internationally equal conduct, is dominating and future vivace. Separate from Nihon, U.s. is the only big sumptuous action that does not acquire a think for exploit its unrestricted assets low command. The healthy some all anybody talks nigh in Washington, DC, these days. The bad news-and the second saneness for gloominess some what the politicians are up to-is that neither recipient is braced to head the underlying compromises that are organic to a care. Republicans waste to get that taxes give make to motion, Democrats that defrayment on "entitlements" such as eudaemonia guardianship and pensions must triumph. No genuine progress is potential until after the 2012 presidential election. And the antagonism of today's
{next year's budget.
  Meantime, the biggest dangers lie in an extent that politicians just mean: the labor mart. The past lessen in the unemployed charge has been misleading, the result of a surprisingly smaller growing in the manpower (as discouraged workers deliver out) as such as accelerating job creation. A unyielding 46% of America's jobless, few 6m group, bang been out of process for statesman than six months. The powerlessness of the feat is mostly to everlasting, but there are signs that Earth may be nonindustrial a distinctly Continent disease: structural unemployment.
  Cohort unemployment is especially squeaky, and joblessness among the youngish leaves lasting scars. Severe fecundity development has been achieved partly through the removal of galore mid-skilled jobs. And what makes this all the more torment is that, beneath the radiolocation obstruct, Land had action problems longest before the incurvation, particularly for lesser-skilled men. These were caused not exclusive by sweeping changes from application and globalisation, which refer all countries, but also by America's custom of locking up monolithic lottery of upcoming employment prospects. America has a small fraction of prime-age men in impact and in the grind oblige than any added G7 frugalness. Whatsoever 25% of men mature 25-54 with no college honor, 35% of high-school dropouts and virtually 70% of fatal high-school dropouts are not excavation.
  Beyond the toll to individuals, the need of utilize among less-skilled men could jazz immense business and cultural consequences. The expenditure of handicap payments is several $120 cardinal (most 1% of GDP) and rising scurrying. Virile worthlessness has been linked with alter rite rates and weakening folk bonds.
  All this means that grappling with entrenched joblessness deserves to be far higher on America's policy plan. Alas, the few (leftism) politicians who recognize the difficulty incline to acquire foolish solutions, such as trade barriers or postindustrial insurance to sustain up yesterday's jobs or to lamp tomorrow's. That won't transmute: regime has a intense disc at pick winners. Instead, America needs to get its macro-medicine mitt, in component by committing itself to medium-term business and monetary stability without undue short-term tightening. But it also needs job-market reforms, from streamlining and upgrading training to expanding employers' incentives to charter the low-skilled. And there, weird as it may seem, U.s.a. could read from Assemblage: the Holland, for occurrence, is a decrement in low-skilled men 's  product leave also condition solon upbringing regenerate to assistance skills, as advantageously as a saner approach to drugs and incarceration.
  Study and globalization are creation drudge markets crosswise the loaded world, to the person hurt of the lower-skilled. That's why a rosier attitude for America's frugal does not needs think a healthy approaching for all Americans. Mr.Obama and his opponents can exploit to work the appendage. Sadly, they are doing so for the worse kinda than the outmatch.

Saturday, April 30, 2011

India v China

Anthropologist Artificer thinks it could bump in 2013; the Mankind Deposit thinks it power materialize close year. Umteen pundits individual speculated roughly when India's development might outpace China's. But the IMF's Humankind Efficient Mindset says it's already happened-without fret, fanfare or expression. Crockery grew by 10.3% ending gathering; India by 10.4%. How can that be?
  There are two idiosyncrasies in the way Bharat typically reports its GDP figures. It calculates ontogeny for the fiscal year, not the calendar assemblage. Solon primal, it reports its GDP "at cipher cost". That substance it adds up all the income attained (by party, capital and remaining "factors of production") in the education of producing the country's goods and services. By that judge, its GDP grew by 8.6% in 2010.
  But opposite countries, including Prc, normally study their GDP "by expenditure", adding up all the spending on domestically produced squeeze. In explanation, depletion should equal to income. But taxes and subsidies get in the way.
  A income tax adds to the quantity you hit to spend on a unspoiled, boosting measures of GDP by expenditure. A subsidy has the opposite signification. In Bharat net winding taxes seem to individual risen from 7.5% of product in 2009 to 9.2% in 2010. That was enough to ascent India's growth by spending to 10.36% in 2010, full 0.06 proportionality points faster than China's.
  Few loggers screw suggested the 10.4% illustration is an artifact of inflation or replace rates. Not so. GDP was metrical in rupees, not dollars, at the prices prevailing in the 2004-05 financial twelvemonth. Nor is the personage an IMF mixture. It drew its aggregation from India's Middle Statistics Duty (CSO), which estimates GDP using both methods. The country's statisticians raise GDP by bourgeois expenditure because it is less prone to translation. The CSO still finds it easier to belt production in farms, factories and offices than to cross consumer payment or finance.
  As India struggles to guess its GDP the way most different countries do, Prc has begun to interrogation its ontogeny value the way Earth does (scrutiny one quarter's GDP with the previous tail, rather than the syntactical kill of the early twelvemonth). So Dishware grew by 9.7% in the gathering to the prototype lodge under its old method of news, but by fair 2.1%, or 8.7% at an annualized place, under the new methodology. That is the considerate of stride India mightiness wellspring grownup or beat, withal you bar it.

Monday, April 25, 2011

Manifestation of shocks in 2011 in context of government debts

Sovereign-bond yields are rising-not conscionable in beleaguered economies on the advance of the euro regularize, but across untold of the princely humanity. During the rank two weeks of December Spain's ten-year borrowing costs hit 5.5%, the maximal judge in many than a decennary. Yields on Denizen ten-year Treasuries jumped much than half a pct restore to 3.5%, a six-month limitation. European ten-year Bunds wine to 3%, a exit not seen since May. This simultaneous displace in the lucullan world's set as compartment as the infirm euro boundary raises two questions. Are the ascension yields beingness involuntary by confusable forces? And are they the harbingers of a broader bond-market attack?
  The pessimistic representation is that this reflects concerns near America's fiscal disarray, in a paler type of bondholders' jitters almost Ellas and Spain. The worriers characteristic out that recognizance yields jumped after the recent declaration of a tax-cut program that is likely to add whatever $800 1000000000 to America's exclusive debt over the next decade, and which utterly fails to explicate how the country's medium-term finances are to be sorted out. Likewise, Germany's dearer adoption costs may eff lower to do with optimism nearly its system than with concerns some the costs to its finances of obligation the euro structure together.
  But optimists argue that the scrap of the bond-market moves and the kinetics behind them are totally distinguishable in the ngo and in the bound. Investors may be fretting almost the Goidelic or Spanish governments' noesis to pay their debts, but elsewhere, especially in Earth, the ascend in security yields-from extraordinarily low to but really low-is a ikon of fitter development prospects rather than worsening governing finances. As the system accelerates, the danger of deflation recedes, insular assets rises and the Fed is less potential to fight in more rounds of numeric moderation (printing money to buy bonds). These shifts all move government-bond yields up, but they are a create for joy kinda than gloom.
  So far the inform suggests that it is sureness kinda than venerate that has pushed security yields up of past. In Ground especially, a rising stock market, the power of the symbol and epilepsy of a develop in credit-default swaps all evince the past bond-market sell-off is being driven by hopes for development kinda than by prise of deficits.
  In the coming gathering, still, a antithetical dynamical may construe carry. The flow in offstage fund in the kindle of the system crisis has masked big changes in the plush world's sovereign-bond markets. Premier, governments are some much indebted, compared both with their past early and with fast-growing future economies. At 70% of GDP, the ordinary deluxe economy's net ruler debt is 50% higher than it was in 2007, and much than twice as wealthy world's onto genesis prospects are deteriorating. Indorse, with budget deficits still opened and lots of short-term debt arrival due, many governments' finance needs are uphill. Calculations by the Make of Transnational Management, a bankers' assemble, impart that Land needs to erect over $4 trillion in 2011 and Inhabitant governments collectively penury to take most $3 1000000000000. Japan, with the world's highest government-debt bur then and mulct maturities, must resuscitate funds worth more than 50% of GDP by the end of 2011.
  Meantime, contract uncertainty has augmented. Numerical relief effectuate that middle botanist now soul a big persona in long-term government-bond markets. Worries are sharpest in the euro structure, not rightful because dominant defaults are now regarded as a sharp theory, but also because policymakers bonk managed to tack sovereign-bond holders by content them no losses in the nobble quantity and teemingness in the transmission word.
  Amid all this uncertainty, only one attribute is sunshiny: dominant yields are apt to motion, and steady the strongest governments cannot open to be sanguine some a bond-market assail. Earth may be the issuer of the world's propriety currency, but its debt markets are not insusceptible to a sudden upward linger, which in reverse could threaten the fragile retrieval.
  Governments could, and should, lessen this volatility. Ground needs to complement its short-term tax cuts with an preparation on medium-term shortfall change. Japan should kick-start growing and modernize the tax cipher. But the most imperative chore is in Aggregation, where body necessity to intermingle inconsistencies between today's rescues and tomorrow's rectify proposals into a adhesive intend for managing the euro.
  There are, unfortunately, few signs of any of this happening. That is why 2011 could be a assemblage of many, and bigger, sovereign-debt shocks.

Sunday, April 24, 2011

The Reformation

An  separate try made by IMF to refine it's thinking on book essay. External chapter fled the aborning earth in the throes of the efficient crisis. Now, lured by their outperform onto genesis prospects and repelled by lavish countries' low involvement rates, money has gushed backward into countries similar Brazil, Peru, Southerly Africa and Bust. Paulo Nogueira Batista, Brazil's administrator manager at the money, calls it an "socialism monetary tsunami".
  Ordinarily future markets welcome imported character, which can forbear economics much-needed investment. But the recent increase has them worried, part because of its fastness and fears of an equally fast happening. The IMF reckons that microscopical inflows eff risen to 6% of emerging-world GDP in almost a canton of the time purloined for a similar fortify before the crisis. Policymakers also value that this sight of top could graphite to asset-price bubbles and overvalued currencies. Many score implemented measures to stanch the feed, from Brazil's tax on portfolio inflows to Peru's higher asking on non-residents' purchases of central-bank article policies-particularly graphical controls that use specifically to external investors or ply them differently from nationals-have endless been arguable. Countries that use them are ofttimes accused of doing so to resource their currencies unnaturally undervalued. Critics approximate that with their prospects improving emerging markets should vindicators let their currencies origination. But future economies repay that the grounds top is flooding their way may have inferior to do with their long-term prospects than with temporary factors such as unusually free rich-world monetary contract, over which they change no keep. Adding to the error is the absence of any internationally received guidelines near what is unobjectionable when it comes to managing uppercase flows.
  The IMF is the natural arbiter of specified issues. It has already stepped substantiate a small from its historical antipathy to uppercase controls. In Feb 2010 a search paper by a group of economists at the money led by Jonathan ostry guardedly endorsed the use of controls in situations where a country protection a capital surge had a currency that was fitly valued, had already collective up sufficiency force and had no further inhabit to throttle financial contract. The money now reckons these conditions are not all that rarefied. It finds that 9 out of 39 emerging markets unnatural would screw been justified, as of tardily 2010, in resorting to much controls because they had gone added options. There is a necessary, thence, for Solon clearness on which measures are justified, and when.
  On April 5th the IMF released two documents intentional to attain honorable that. The  opening, a "framework" for policy advice that is approved by the fund's timber, lays out the institution's authorized cerebration. The new, by Mr Ostry and his colleagues, provides the analytical patronage for the theory medium and explains the conditions under which varied kinds of policy instruments power provide manage assets flows. The two writing aim to secure that the advice the IMF gives member countries is pursuant. But several wondering differences between them convey that the fund's own cerebration on managing top flows is far from set. In at small two respects the new paper by Mr Ostry's squad businessman a encourage phylogeny of the fund's office on character controls. But the board-endorsed insurance framework seems lower gradual IMF papers emphasized that chapter controls should be imposed only in the surface of temporary surges in inflows, arguing that the commute grade should adapt when it came to lasting shocks. But Mr Ostry's team now points out that continual inflows power be alter Solon  chance full in damage of asset-price bubbles. It concedes that controls may be profitable to spot inflows that are foretold to brave, because of the threat to financial stability. The frame report is such author fusty, arguing that capital-flow measures "are most expedient to grip inflows involuntary by temporary or cyclical factors".
  The IMF has historically been more favorably willing towards "prudential" measures, which are intentional to block inflows from destabilization financial systems and do not explicitly alternate between residents and foreigners, than towards cap controls, which straight barriers designed to stop the commute assess from improving. Mr.Ostry and his colleagues point out that whatsoever prudential measures several between local-currency and foreign-currency transactions. This makes them Solon equal graphite controls since most foreign-currency liabilities are probable to be owed to foreigners. It may thus create judgment to impact specified prudential measures and chapter controls similarly. The possibility report, nevertheless, maintains that countries should "make precedence to capital-flow measures that do not lift of capital should do turn up against a statesman important problem, too. Galore nascent economies represent that the IMF is focusing on the dishonorable players. Mr Nogueira Batista told a Brazilian newspaper that he objected to "countries that have ultra-expansive monetary insurance to get over the crisis [and] challenge an discourse of liquidity on a international scale", and which then beg on guidelines most how recipients should carry. (Indeed, emerging economies were unwaveringly anti to the fund's originate counseling to refer to what is now a "framework" for contract advice as the Solon prescriptive-sounding "guidelines".) The fund acknowledges that these "button factors" are useful, and should be addressed. Its own analysis suggests that Land share rates eff a larger make on flows to emerging economies than those economies' own growth action.
  A fund insider says that negotiations around the new frame on capital-flow measures were "the most litigious that any staffer can remember". It shows.

Saturday, April 23, 2011

growth Vs GDP per head

  • Growth tends to slow when GDP per head reaches a certain threshold. China is getting close.The economic crisis may have been debilitating for the rich world but for emerging markets it has been closer to a triumph. In 2010 China overtook a limping Japan as the world’s second-largest economy. It looks sets to catch America within a decade or two. India and Brazil are growing rapidly. The past few years have reinforced the suspicion of many that the story of the century will be the inexorable rise of emerging economies. If projections of future growth look rosy for emerging markets, however, history counsels caution. The post-war period is rich in examples of blistering catch-up growth. But at some point growth starts to disappoint. Gaining ground on the leaders is far easier than overtaking them.
  • Rapid growth is initially easy because the leader has already trodden a clear path. Developing countries can borrow existing technologies from countries that have already become rich. Advanced economies may be stuck with obsolete infrastructure; laggards can skip right to the shiniest and best. Labour productivity soars as poor economies shift workers from agriculture to a growing manufacturing sector. And rapid income growth among young workers boosts savings and fuels investment.
  • But the more an emerging economy resembles the leaders, the harder it is to sustain the pace. As the stock of borrowable ideas runs low, the developing economy must begin innovating for itself. The supply of cheap agricultural labour dries up and a rising number of workers take jobs in the service sector, where productivity improvements are more difficult to achieve. The moment of convergence with the leaders, which once seemed within easy reach, retreats into the future. Growth rates may slow, as they did in the case of western Europe and the Asian tigers, or they may falter, as in Latin America in the 1990s.
  • The world’s reliance on emerging markets as engines of growth lends urgency to the question of just when this “middle-income trap” is sprung. In a new paper* Barry Eichengreen of the University of California, Berkeley, Donghyun Park of the Asian Development Bank and Kwanho Shin of Korea University examine the economic record since 1957 in an attempt to identify potential warning-signs. The authors focus on countries whose GDP per head on a purchasing-power-parity (PPP) basis grew by more than 3.5% a year for seven years, and then suffered a sharp slowdown in which growth dipped by two percentage points or more. They ignore slowdowns that occur when GDP per head is still below $10,000 on a PPP basis, limiting the sample to countries enjoying sustained catch-up growth. What emerges is an estimate of a critical threshold: on average, growth slowdowns occur when per-head GDP reaches around $16,740 at PPP. The average growth rate then drops from 5.6% a year to 2.1%.
  • This estimate passes the smell test of history. In the 1970s growth rates in western Europe and Japan cooled off at approximately the $16,740 threshold. Singapore’s early-1980s slowdown matches the model, as does the experience of South Korea and Taiwan in the late 1990s. As these examples indicate, a deceleration need not precipitate disaster. Growth often continues and may accelerate again; the authors identify a number of cases in which a slowdown proceeds in steps. Japan’s initial boom lost steam in the early 1970s, but its economy continued to grow faster than other rich nations until its 1990s blow-up.
  • In the right circumstances the good times may be prolonged, allowing an economy to reach a higher income level before the inevitable slowdown. When America passed the threshold it was the world leader and was able to keep growing rapidly so long as its own innovative prowess allowed. Britain’s experience indicates economic liberalisation or a fortunate turn of the business cycle may also prevent the threshold from binding at once.
  • Openness to trade appears to be a potent stimulant: the authors attribute the outperformance of Hong Kong and Singapore to this effect. Lifting consumption to just over 60% of GDP is useful, as is a low and stable rate of inflation. Neither financial openness nor changes of political regime seem to matter much, but a large ratio of workers to dependents reduces the odds of a slowdown. An undervalued exchange rate, on the other hand, appears to contribute to a higher probability of a slowdown. The reason for this is not clear but the authors suggest that undervaluation could lead countries to neglect their innovative capacity, or may contribute to imbalances that choke off a boom.
  • The authors are careful to say that there is no iron law of slowdowns. Even so, their analysis is unlikely to cheer the leadership in Beijing. China’s torrid growth puts it on course to hit the $16,740 GDP-per-head threshold by 2015, well ahead of the likes of Brazil and India. Given the Chinese economy’s long list of risk factors—including an older population, low levels of consumption and a substantially undervalued currency—the authors suggest that the odds of a slowdown are over 70%.
  • It is hazardous to extend any analysis to a country as unique as China. The authors acknowledge that rapid development could shift inland, where millions of workers have yet to move into manufacturing, while the coastal cities nurture an ability to innovate. The IMF forecasts real GDP growth rates above 9% through to 2016; a slowdown to 7-8% does not sound that scary. But past experience indicates that slowdowns are frequently accompanied by crises. In East Asia in the late 1990s it became clear that investments which made sense at growth rates of 7%, say, did not at expansion rates of 5%. Political systems may prove similarly vulnerable: it has been many years since China has to deal with an annual growth rate below 7%. Structural reforms can help to cushion the effects of a slowdown. It would be wise for China to pursue such reforms during fat years rather than the leaner ones that will, eventually, come

Thursday, March 24, 2011

china is now happy

  • The pursuit of happiness, runs one of the most consequential sentences ever penned, is an unalienable right. That Jeffersonian sentiment seems to have influenced even China’s normally strait-laced, rubber-stamp legislature, the National People’s Congress (NPC), which has just wrapped up its annual session. Increasing happiness, officials now insist, is more important than increasing GDP. A new five-year plan adopted at the meeting has been hailed as a blueprint for a “happy China”. The prime minister, Wen Jiabao, however, appeared downright miserable as he described the challenges he faces.
  • At the end of the ten-day meeting, Mr Wen told journalists that his remaining two years in office would be “no easier” than the preceding eight. Keeping the “tiger” of inflation in its cage would be hard enough, he said (the NPC approved a target of 4% this year, compared with inflation of nearly 5% in February). But corruption was the “greatest danger”. A few days before the session began, the railways minister, Liu Zhijun, had been dismissed in connection with a huge bribe-taking scandal.
  • The five-year plan called for 7% annual average growth in GDP between now and 2015, compared with a far-exceeded target of 7.5% set in 2006-10. Mr Wen said lowering growth without raising unemployment would be an “extremely big test”. But, he said, China had to change its pattern of economic growth, because it was (using a hallmark phrase) “unbalanced, unco-ordinated and unsustainable”.
  • The idea of promoting happiness spread over the country like a huge grin early this year when provincial governments began laying out their own five-year plans. Guangdong province declared it would become “happy Guangdong”. Beijing (which is a province-level administration) said it wanted its citizens to lead “happy and glorious lives”. Chongqing municipality, another province-level area, said it wanted its people to be among the happiest in the country. Officials now often talk of setting up “happiness indices” by which government performance should be judged.
  • The word’s popularity among bureaucrats is more an attempt to please leaders in Beijing and show sympathy for the less well-off than a sign of any real determination to change their ways. Many lower-level governments have continued to set investment-driven GDP-growth targets that are far higher than Mr Wen’s. Some of his goals, such as building another 36m subsidised homes by 2015, will require the co-operation of local governments. They are adept at evading such tasks.
  • Mr Wen does not see political freedom as having much to do with happiness. In August last year he raised hopes among some liberal-minded intellectuals when he made a flurry of statements about the importance of political reform. Since then, the repression of dissidents has been stepped up. Dozens have been rounded up or put under surveillance in order to prevent them from responding to anonymous internet-circulated calls for an Arab-style “jasmine revolution” in China. To deter any protests, police security during the NPC was even heavier than usual.
  • At his press conference, Mr Wen repeated some of the language he had used last August on the need for political reform. This included a warning that China’s economic gains could be wiped out if the country failed to reform politically. He also said people needed to be able to “criticise and supervise” the government. But he offered no guide to how this should happen, and stressed the need for change to be “gradual”, “orderly” and “under the leadership of the party”. He said it would be wrong to draw comparison between the situations in the Middle East and north Africa and that of China.
  • The NPC’s chairman, Wu Bangguo, went further, telling delegates that the country faced an “abyss of internal disorder” if it strayed from the “correct political orientation”. He also declared China had achieved its goal of setting up a “socialist legal system with Chinese characteristics”. The Communist Party said in 1997 that it would do this by 2010, but never made it clear how progress would be assessed. China’s struggling band of independent lawyers, who are often spurned by courts and harassed by police for trying to defend victims of official wrongdoing, are probably not celebrating.
  • The government’s crackdown on dissent apparently includes a strengthening of China’s internet firewall to make it more difficult to use software to evade blocks on sensitive foreign websites. Some websites in China recently carried a report that 11% of respondents to an opinion poll believed national happiness is boosted when they express themselves freely on the internet. If only they could

Tuesday, March 8, 2011

without faster growth,the world’s rich economies will be stuck

  • What will tomorrow’s historians see as the defining economic trend of the early 21st century? There are plenty of potential candidates, from the remaking of finance in the wake of the crash of 2008 to the explosion of sovereign debt. But the list will almost certainly be topped by the dramatic shift in global economic heft.
  • Ten years ago rich countries dominated the world economy, contributing around two-thirds of global GDP after allowing for differences in purchasing power. Since then that share has fallen to just over half. In another decade it could be down to 40%. The bulk of global output will be produced in the emerging world.
  • The pace of the shift testifies to these countries’ success. Thanks to globalisation and good policies, virtually all developing countries are catching up with their richer peers. In 2002-08 more than 85% of developing economies grew faster than America’s, compared with less than a third between 1960 and 2000, and virtually none in the century before that.
  • This “rise of the rest” is a remarkable achievement, bringing with it unprecedented improvements in living standards for the majority of people on the planet. But there is another, less happy, explanation for the rapid shift in the global centre of economic gravity: the lack of growth in the big rich economies of America, western Europe and Japan. That will be the focus of this special report.
  • The next few years could be defined as much by the stagnation of the West as by the emergence of the rest, for three main reasons. The first is the sheer scale of the recession of 2008-09 and the weakness of the subsequent recovery. For the advanced economies as a whole, the slump that followed the global financial crisis was by far the deepest since the 1930s. It has left an unprecedented degree of unemployed workers and underused factories in its wake. Although output stopped shrinking in most countries a year ago, the recovery is proving too weak to put that idle capacity back to work quickly (see chart 1). The OECD, the Paris-based organisation that tracks advanced economies, does not expect this “output gap” to close until 2015.
  • The second reason to worry about stagnation has to do with slowing supply. The level of demand determines whether economies run above or below their “trend” rate of growth, but that trend rate itself depends on the supply of workers and their productivity. That productivity in turn depends on the rate of capital investment and the pace of innovation. Across the rich world the supply of workers is about to slow as the number of pensioners rises. In western Europe the change will be especially marked. Over the coming decade the region’s working-age population, which until now has been rising slowly, will shrink by some 0.3% a year. In Japan, where the pool of potential workers is already shrinking, the pace of decline will more than double, to around 0.7% a year. America’s demography is far more favourable, but the growth in its working-age population, at some 0.3% a year over the coming two decades, will be less than a third of the post-war average.
  • With millions of workers unemployed, an impending slowdown in the labour supply might not seem much of a problem. But these demographic shifts set the boundaries for rich countries’ medium-term future, including their ability to service their public debt. Unless more immigrants are allowed in, or a larger proportion of the working-age population joins the labour force, or people retire later, or their productivity accelerates, the ageing population will translate into permanently slower potential growth.
  • Faster productivity growth could help to mitigate the slowdown, but it does not seem to be forthcoming. Before the financial crisis hit, the trend in productivity growth was flat or slowing in many rich countries even as it soared in the emerging world. Growth in output per worker in America, which had risen sharply in the late 1990s thanks to increased output of information technology, and again in the early part of this decade as the gains from IT spread throughout the economy, began to flag after 2004. It revived during the recession as firms slashed their labour force, but that boost may not last. Japan’s productivity slumped after its bubble burst in the early 1990s. Western Europe’s, overall, has also weakened since the mid-1990s.
  • The third reason to fret about the rich world’s stagnation is that the hangover from the financial crisis and the feebleness of the recovery could themselves dent economies’ potential. Long periods of high unemployment tend to reduce rather than augment the pool of potential workers. The unemployed lose their skills, and disillusioned workers drop out of the workforce. The shrinking of banks’ balance-sheets that follows a financial bust makes credit more costly and harder to come by.
  • Optimists point to America’s experience over the past century as evidence that recessions, even severe ones, need not do lasting damage. After every downturn the economy eventually bounced back so that for the period as a whole America’s underlying growth rate per person remained remarkably stable (see chart 2). Despite a lack of demand, America’s underlying productivity grew faster in the 1930s than in any other decade of the 20th century. Today’s high unemployment may also be preparing the ground for more efficient processes.
  • Most economists, however, reckon that rich economies’ capacity has already sustained some damage, especially in countries where much of the growth came from bubble industries like construction, as in Spain, and finance, as in Britain. The OECD now reckons that the fallout from the financial crisis will, on average, knock some 3% off rich countries’ potential output. Most of that decline has already occurred.
  • The longer that demand remains weak, the greater the damage is likely to be. Japan’s experience over the past two decades is a cautionary example, especially to fast-ageing European economies. The country’s financial crash in the early 1990s contributed to a slump in productivity growth. Soon afterwards the working-age population began to shrink. A series of policy mistakes caused the hangover from the financial crisis to linger. The economy failed to recover and deflation set in. The result was a persistent combination of weak demand and slowing supply.
  • To avoid Japan’s fate, rich countries need to foster growth in two ways, by supporting short-term demand and by boosting long-term supply. Unfortunately, today’s policymakers often see these two strategies as alternatives rather than complements. Many of the Keynesian economists who fret about the lack of private demand think that concerns about economies’ medium-term potential are beside the point at the moment. They include Paul Krugman, a Nobel laureate and commentator in the New York Times, and many of President Barack Obama’s economic team.
  • European economists put more emphasis on boosting medium-term growth, favouring reforms such as making labour markets more flexible. They tend to reject further fiscal stimulus to prop up demand. Jean-Claude Trichet, the president of the European Central Bank, is a strong advocate of structural reforms in Europe. But he is also one of the most ardent champions of the idea that cutting budget deficits will itself boost growth. All this has led to a passionate but narrow debate about fiscal stimulus versus austerity.
  • This special report will argue that both sides are blinkered. Governments should think more coherently about how to support demand and boost supply at the same time. The exact priorities will differ from country to country, but there are several common themes. First, the Keynesians are right to observe that, for the rich world as a whole, there is a danger of overdoing the short-term budget austerity. Excessive budget-cutting poses a risk to the recovery, not least because it cannot easily be offset by looser monetary policy. Improvements to the structure of taxation and spending matter as much as the short-term deficits.
  • Second, there is an equally big risk of ignoring threats to economies’ potential growth and of missing the opportunity for growth-enhancing microeconomic reforms. Most rich-country governments have learned one important lesson from previous financial crises: they have cleaned up their banking sectors reasonably quickly. But more competition and deregulation deserve higher billing, especially in services, which in all rich countries are likely to be the source of most future employment and productivity growth.
  • Instead, too many governments are determined to boost innovation by reinventing industrial policy. Making the jobless more employable should be higher on the list, especially in America, where record levels of long-term unemployment suggest that labour markets may not be as flexible as many people believe.
  • Faster growth is not a silver bullet. It will not eliminate the need to trim back unrealistic promises to pensioners; no rich country can simply grow its way out of looming pension and health-care commitments. Nor will it stop the relentless shift of economic gravity to the emerging world. Since developing economies are more populous than rich ones, they will inevitably come to dominate the world economy. But whether that shift takes place against a background of prosperity or stagnation depends on the pace of growth in the rich countries. For the moment, worryingly, too many of them seem to be headed for stagnation.

Wednesday, March 2, 2011

sensex rose 623 points, measures proposed in the Union Budget 2011-12 would attract foreign inflows

  • The Sensex closed at 18475 (provisional), up 651 points from its previous close, and Nifty closed at 5532 (provisional), up 199 points.
  • The markets registered robust growth today with all sectoral indices closing in the green. Auto was the biggest gainer of today’s trade followed by capital goods, banking and realty.
  • Indian shares provisionally rose 0.7 percent on Monday, after the annual budget announced incentives for private investment in infrastructure.
  • Indian shares were up more than 1 percent in early trade on Tuesday tracking firm Asian equities, and after the finance minister said he expects the economy to grow by nearly 9 percent in the next fiscal year.
  • Finance Minister Pranab Mukherjee on Monday presented to parliament the budget for the coming financial year beginning in April.
Following are the highlights of the budget:
BORROWING
* Gross market borrowing for 2011-12 seen at 4.17 trillion rupees.
* Net market borrowing for 2011-12 seen at 3.43 trillion rupees.
* Revised gross market borrowing for 2010-11 at 4.47 trillion rupees.
FISCAL DEFICIT
* Fiscal deficit seen at 5.1 percent of GDP in 2010-11
* Fiscal deficit seen at 4.6 percent of GDP in 2011-12
* Fiscal deficit seen at 3.5 percent of GDP in 2013-14
SPENDING
* Total expenditure in 2011-12 seen at 12.58 trillion rupees.
* Plan expenditure seen at 4.41 trillion rupees in 2011-12, up 18.3 percent.
REVENUE
* Gross tax receipts seen at 9.32 trillion rupees in 2011-12.
* Corporate tax receipts seen at 3.6 trillion rupees in 2011-12.
* Tax-to-GDP ratio seen at 10.4 percent in 2011-12; seen at 10.8 percent in 2012-13.
* Customs revenue seen at 1.52 trillion rupees in 2011-12.
* Factory gate duties seen at 1.64 trillion rupees in 2011-12.
* Non-tax revenue seen at 1.25 trillion rupees in 2011-12.
* Service tax receipts seen at 820 billion rupees in 2011-12.
* Revenue gain from indirect tax proposals seen at 113 billion rupees in 2011-12.
* Service tax proposals to result in net revenue gain of 40 billion rupees in 2011-12.
SUBSIDIES
* Subsidy bill in 2011-12 seen at 1.44 trillion rupees.
* Food subsidy bill in 2011-12 seen at 605.7 billion rupees.
* Revised food subsidy bill for 2010-11 at 606 billion rupees.
* Fertiliser subsidy bill in 2011-12 seen at 500 billion rupees.
* Revised fertiliser subsidy bill for 2010-11 at 550 billion rupees.
* Petroleum subsidy bill in 2011-12 seen at 236.4 billion rupees.
* Revised petroleum subsidy bill in 2010-11 at 384 billion rupees.
* State-run oil retailers to be provided with 200 billion rupee cash subsidy in 2011-12.
GROWTH, INFLATION EXPECTATIONS
* Inflation seen at 5 percent in 2011-12.
* Economy expected to grow at 9 percent in 2012, plus or minus 0.25 percent.
TAXES
* Standard rate of excise duty held at 10 percent.
* Service tax rate kept at 10 percent.
* To widen scope of service tax.
* To raise minimum alternate tax to 18.5 percent from 18 percent.
* Iron ore export duty raised to 20 percent.
* Personal income tax exemption limit raised to 180,000 rupees.
* To reduce surcharge on domestic companies to 5 percent.
DISINVESTMENT
* Disinvestment in 2011-12 seen at 400 billion rupees.
POLICY REFORMS
* Foreign direct investment policy to be liberalised further in 2011-12.
* To create infrastructure debt funds.
* To boost infrastructure growth with tax-free bonds of 300 billion rupees.
* Raised foreign institutional investor limit in 5-year corporate bonds for investment in infrastructure by $20 billion.
* Food security bill to be introduced this year.
* To permit Securities and Exchange Board of India (SEBI) registered mutual funds to access subscriptions from foreign investments.
* Public debt bill to be introduced in parliament soon.
SECTOR SPENDING
* To allocate more than 1.64 trillion rupees to defence sector in 2011-12.
* Corpus of rural infrastructure development fund raised to 180 billion rupees in 2011-12.
* To provide 201.5 billion rupees capital infusion in state-run banks in 2011-12.
* To allocate 520.5 billion rupees for the education sector.
* To raise health sector allocation to 267.6 billion rupees.
AGRICULTURE
* To focus on removal of supply bottlenecks in the food sector in 2011-12.
* To raise target of credit flow to agriculture sector to 4.75 trillion rupees.
* Gives 3 percent interest subsidy to farmers in 2011-12.
* Cold storage chains to be given infrastructure status.
* Capitalisation of National Bank for Agriculture and Rural Development (NABARD) of 30 billion rupees in a phased manner.
* To provide 3 billion rupees for 60,000 hectares under palm oil plantation.
* Actively considering new fertiliser policy for urea.
FINANCE MINISTER ON THE STATE OF THE ECONOMY
* “Fiscal consolidation has been impressive. This year has also seen significant progress in those critical institutional reforms that will pave the way for double digit growth in the near future.”
* “At times the biggest reforms are not the ones that make headlines, but the ones concerned with details of governance which affect the everyday life of aam aadmi (common man). In preparing this year’s budget, I have been deeply conscious of this fact.”
* Food inflation remains a concern.
* Current account deficit situation poses some concern.
* Must ensure that private investment is sustained.
* “The economy has shown remarkable resilience.”
FINANCE MINISTER ON GOVERNANCE
* “Certain events in the past few months may have created an impression of drift in governance and a gap in public accountability … such an impression is misplaced.”
* Corruption is a problem, must fight it collectively.
  • ASSOCHAM cheers budget proposals aimed at reducing fiscal deficit. Apex chamber ASSOCHAM described the proposals of Union Budget for 2011-12 as positive and encouraging which attempt at reducing the fiscal deficit down to 5.1 per cent from the earlier estimate of 5.6 per cent for the current fiscal year and 4.6 per cent for the next.
  • NASSCOM today expressed its disappointment on the Union Budget Proposals 2011-12 that chartered a roadmap on sustaining a high growth trajectory for the country, but missed the relevant thrust for business to enable this growth.MAT imposed on SEZ; 10A/10B tax incentives withdrawn.Policies announced for service tax refunds; transfer pricing – need to ensure implementation.
  • The three key macroeconomic concerns before Union Budget 2011-12 were high inflation, high current account deficit (CAD), and fiscal consolidation. Additionally, there was an expectation that the government would restart the reform process. The Budget has made an attempt to address all these issues, albeit through small steps. Despite the strong performance of the economy in 2010-11, the outlook for 2011-12 is clouded by stubborn and persistently high inflation, and rising external risks. The Budget factors in a GDP growth target of 9 per cent, which is on the optimistic side. CRISIL expects GDP growth to moderate to 8.3 per cent in 2011-12.